Housing Standards 2004/2005
|
Factors affecting demand | Effect on demand | Factors affecting supply | Effect on supply |
Real housing price | - | Real housing price | + |
Current income | + | Future (expected) housing price | + |
Future income | + | Price of land | - |
Expected capital appreciation | + | Price of other input (labour, materials) | - |
Income tax rate | - | Probability that a certain portion of production (of the supply) will be sold in advance | + |
Interest rates | - | Share of production sold in advance | + |
Interest rates | - |
Note: the signs in the first and fourth columns indicate the effect of the given factor on demand and supply respectively. For example, a rise in the prices of residential real estate leads (other things being the same) to a fall in the demand for housing and conversely to an increase in the housing supply. The cited relationships are based on economic theory and are not the result of estimated parameters of specific supply and demand functions.
Source: Kenny (2003: 17,22), modified.
According to Meen (Sullivan, Gibb 2003) the most frequently used method of estimateing long-term price developments is the empirical rule combined with the price-to-income ratio (P/I). Although the majority of studies (Garratt 2001, Case, Shiller 2003, PricewaterhouseCoopers 2002, PricewaterhouseCoopers 2004) point to household income as one of the main factors influencing housing prices in the long term, it is far from the only factor. Meen notes that, particularly after 1990, estimates of price developments in the United Kingdom, especially in the short term, based only on the value of the P/I, were unreliable.
Another indicator used to determine national housing prices and estimate price developments (e.g. Holt 2003) is the price-to-earnings ratio (P/E), which is similar to the indicator regularly used in stock market in the assessment of shares. As with shares, in the case of real estate this approach is based on the assumption that the price of real estate is a function of the expected future returns on this real estate. However, in the case of real estate these returns are more difficult to quantify than, for example, in the case of stocks and bonds. The reverse value of the P/E indicator is the also used rent-to-price ratio indicator (used by McCarthy and Peach 2004).
Weeken (2004) explains housing price increases in the United Kingdom in recent years in an alternative way also using the model of capital asset pricing, which he applies to the housing market. He bases this approach on the Dividend Discount Model, which is used to value publicly traded stocks. A simple dividend discount model assumes that the correct value of a stock can be determined as the sum of the expected returns from this stock (i.e. future paid dividends) discounted to the present point in time. In the case of housing it is assumed that the national value of a house or flat can be determined as the sum of future discounted net returns in the form of rent. In the case of housing the dividend is that part of the net rent that is not re-invested into housing.
Meen (Sullivan, Gibb 2003) notes that analysts focus mainly on models drawn from neoclassical economics. The real "correct" price of a house/flat is determined as a quotient, where the nominator is the expected implicit income from rent and the denominator is the costs of owner-occupied housing. The relationship is formally expressed with the following equation:
where:
g(t) - the real purchasing price of a house/flat over time t,
R(t) - the real income from implicit rent over time t,
- the marginal household tax rate,
i(t) - market interest rate on loans,
- inflation rate,
- expected rate of real estate depreciation (costs of repair, maintenance and running of the house/flat),
ge/g(t) - expected real capital valorisation (the real increase in real estate prices).
Housing is considered equivalent to any other kind of financial asset. No lags are included in the equation (e.g. inflation rate from the previous period ), in other words, it is assumed that the housing market is efficient and that prices respond to price-forming information. With only few exception there is not empirical model that estimates the amount of the cited equation directly, especially as the implicit rent R(t) cannot be measured directly; usually it is replaced by a function:
R(t) = h [RY(t), W(t), HH(t), H(t)]
where
RY - the real disposable income per person per household,
W - real household wealth,
HH - number of households,
H - housing stock size.
The models based on the equations presented above and derived from neo-classical economics are substantially more comprehensive than using just one single indicator (e.g. P/I), but again in the case of the United Kingdom they produced results that were not very reliable, especially over the course of the 1990s and especially for predictions of price developments in the short term (for the next several years).
The main reason why the neoclassical models based on fundamental economic factors, in particular from the level of real household income, lost strength in the 1990s was that they did not explain the short-term price fluctuations, i.e. short-term price deviations from the price equilibrium (price bubbles). Today three explanations are considered to account for this: first, it is caused by the speculative behaviour of investors in the housing market; second, too much state or local intervention and regulation in the field of housing construction; third, the existence of substantial transaction costs associated with the acquisition of housing.
In recent years talk has centred mostly on the influence of the speculations of investors, the first of the above-mentioned reasons why the rise or fall in prices cannot be predicted in the short term purely on the basis of fundamental economic factors. A more detailed analysis of the efficiency of the housing market has shown that residential real-estate price developments are to a large degree a self-determining process. What prices will be like next years has been shown to depend, not only on fundamental economic factors, but also on what prices were like last year, the years before, and even three years earlier. If housing prices can be predicted on the basis of past price developments, then it is possible with just some knowledge of price changes to attain abnormally high profits, afflicting the housing market with considerable inefficiency - among other things, it can no longer satisfy a basic precondition of neo-liberal economic models.
If the behaviour of buyers in the housing market is motivated mainly by an optimistic outlook, which means a quick and stable price increase in the future, then the level the prices is currently at is logically unsustainable in the long term. Prices cannot rise interminably, and the moment investors get the impression that price growth has stopped, and that prices could even begin to fall again, the bubble bursts. Price bubbles are to a considerable degree the result of human psychology - of expectations about future price developments, individual theories about potential risks from a fall in prices, concerns about being ousted from the market in the future, and so on. Some researchers (Case, Shiller 2003), therefore, believe that it is important to study how people think when they are making fundamental economic decisions such as purchasing a house or flat.
Current housing research has succeeded in incorporating even short-term price fluctuations into its models and has thus managed to make its predictions somewhat more precise. In this case the simulation method is the error correction model, which was used, for example, by Meen (2002), Hort (1998), Pagés and Maza (2003) and many others in their analyses of prices. The model is divided into two sub-models, two equations: a sub-model dealing with long-term developments of "equilibrium" housing prices, predicted in a manner similar to that used in classic neo-liberal models, with the aid of fundamental economic factors; and a sub-model dealing with short-term housing price developments predicted on the basis of housing price changes in recent years (reflecting the auto-correlation of prices in the short term) and with the aid of a correction coefficient.